조직관리론

Pisano (1990)

제설자 2019. 3. 9. 01:59

Abstract

Theory: Sources of transaction costs

1) Small-numbers-bargaining hazards

2) Appropriability concerns


Subject: Established firms' choices between in-house and external sources of R&D 

when technological change shifts the locus of R&D expertise from established enterprise to new entrants,

and established firms face a make-or-buy decision for R&D projects


+ Contingency on the R&D procurement decision


Sample:

92 biotechnology R&D projects 

that major pharmaceutical companies have sponsored either in-house or through external contractual arrangements


Result:

1) Small-numbers-bargaining hazards: Small-numbers-bargaining problems -> Internalize R&D

2) Appropriability concerns: Firm's R&D experience / Dependence on the pharmaceutical business / National origin -> Decision


* Introduction

Literature

A: In-house R&D VS B: Contractual arrangements (Licenses, R&D agreements, and Joint ventures)

A - Mowery 1983

A vs B: von Hippel 1982; Bozeman and Link 1983; Pavitt 1986


Background

Broad and: rapid changes in the core technologies ("Creative destruction") -> R&D procurement decisions


The past application of transaction cost

1) Production and supply activities: Monteverde and Teece, 1982a, 1982b; Stuckey, 1983; Masten, 1984; Walker and Weber, 1984; Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt, 1986; Joskow, 1987 

2) Marketing: Anderson and Schmittlein, 1984 


Technology?

R&D = Hierarchy > Markets: Williamson (1975), Teece and Armour (1977), Teece (1988)

The best location for R&D

Examine with the project-level data 

Not with Individual components and subassemblies (Monteverde and Teece, 1982a; Masten, 1984; Walker and Weber, 1984 )


Potential sources of transaction costs

Engineering intensity and design specialization (Monteverde and Teece, 1982a, 1982b; Masten, 1984)

Technological uncertainty (Walker and Weber, 1984; Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt, 1986)

Co-location of specialized assets (Joskow, 1987) 


This paper

1) small numbers-bargaining hazards stemming from specialized R&D capabilities (Previous: intermediate product markets)

2) appropriability problems arising from competition in product markets. (Schumpeter, 1975; Arrow, 1962; Teece 1986, 1988) 


Topic: The decisions of establihse pharmaceutical companies to develop new biotechnology-based pharmaceutical products through in-house R&D versus through contractual arrangements with outside firms

Biotechnology in pharmaceutical firms: the relatively dramatic changes in the technological environment

Start-up firms in the biotechnology industry have chosen to commercialize the technologies Shan (1989)

Competitive position -> Decision whether to commercialize its technologies on its own or through a cooperative arrangement with a partner

The determinants of cooperative commercialization strategies

# Speed: Red-Queen competition


Current 

The R&D procurement behavior of large established firms already capable of commercializing the technology

1) The transactional difficulties of R&D contracts

2) How these difficulties affect established firms' R&D procurement


* Technological changes and the boundaries of the firm


Technological changes

"Competence-destroying" technological change (Tushman and Anderson, 1986)

The locus of technical expertise: Industry incumbent -> Newly formed ventures and firms from other industries

"Creative destruction" Schumpeter (1975)

+ "Revolutionary" technological change (Abernathy and Clark, 1985) which weakens or destroys established firms' advantages in R&D and production has little or no effect on their relative advantage in distribution and marketing -> differences in distinctive competences

A competitive clash (X), Opportunities for beneficial trade (O)


Background

The emergence of biotechnology during the late 1970s for the pharmaceutical industry

: Biotechnology as a competence-destroying technology

Most of the early commercial biotechnology R&D

: by new ventures that formed in the United States between 1976 and 1982 and 

: not by the established pharmaceutical firms (Office of Technology Assessment, 1984)


Duality

Biotechnology was competence destroying on the R&D end, it was competence preserving at the commercialization end.

Must all go through the same clinical tests and regulatory approval process and are sold through the same distribution channels as traditional drug

Established pharmaceutical companies with years of commercial experience and existing organizational capabilities in these "downstream" functions (bringing new drugs from the laboratory to the market)


Economies of functional or vertical specialization

Efficiency: In-house vertical integration < Procure the services from a new biotechnology firm 


Counterexample

However, established pharmaceutical companies undertook biotechnology R&D projects internally 

Established pharmaceutical firms were conducting slightly less than half (47 percent) of their biotechnology R&D projects in-house.

Factors that have affected the extent and direction of backward integration into biotechnology R&D by individual pharmaceutical companies and, 

How transaction costs may have impeded markets for biotechnology R&D.


- Transaction-cost theory


Why institutional structures other than markets are necessary for the efficient governance of economic activity

Markets > Hierarchies: Economies of specialization and the administrative and incentive limits (Williamson, 1985; Grossman and Hart, 1986)

Hierarchies > Markets: Special circumstances (e.g., Williamson, 1975, 1985; Klein, Crawford, and Alchian, 1978; Teece, 1982)

ex. 1 Uncertainty (when the contingencies affecting the execution of the agreement are complex and difficult for the trading partners to understand, predict, or articulate) and 2 Transaction-specific assets 

1 When unexpected contingencies occur -> Renegotiation

1 + 2 A hazardous situation with Small-numbers-bargaining problem (Williamson, 1975): limited exchange alternatives

: when a firm invests in assets that are costly to transfer to alternative transactions or uses

: Limit the firm's ability to switch partners, make it vulnerable to opportunistic recontracting


Repeatedly entering into contractual agreements that involve uncertainty and transaction-specific asset

-> An incentive for vertical integration

Eliminates the ex-post bargaining problems that might arise with an outside partner and thus improves incentives to commit specialized capital.

Governance economies > The incremental economic costs (due to additional administrative burdens, incentive distortions, and losses in production efficiency that occur when a firm's in-house capabilities are inferior to those of outside sources Williamson, 1985; Grossman and Hart, 1986)


Transaction cost theory

R&D boundary choices that occur in the wake of technological changes

Structural -> Opportunities for trade between firm

Why firms may vertically integrate despite the benefits of trading with external parties


- Transaction costs in markets for biotechnology R&D


Sequential adaption

The uncertainties of R&D pervades and can only be resolved sequentially as the project progresses (Nelson and Winter, 1977)

Futile to attempt to lock-in the terms of trade at the outset, generally agree to renegotiate the contract instead.


Recurrent transaction and hazards

Repeated rounds of negotiation during a single project

Start-up costs of vertical integration make it desirable only for recurring transactions and not for one-time exchanges

Two types of contractual hazards that may lead to vertical integration: 

1) small-numbers bargaining 

2) appropriability problems.


1) Small-numbers bargaining 

Reimbursement of R&D costs, distribution of property rights, and completion dates

The sponsor's options for transferring the project to an alternative supplier 

-> transaction-specificity of investments and the opportunism of the R&D supplier


Tacit knowledge

Media cannot capture the tacit dimensions of the relevant technological know-how (Teece, 1976)

-> Transferring a project from one R&D partner to another will involve some losses in progress

The magnitude of these losses will depend on whether the new R&D partner has some experience or capabilities in the same product application area


Alternative supplier

1) if a sponsor has alternative suppliers with relevant R&D experience, it can better preserve the value of its original R&D investment in the event that the agreement with the initial contractor is terminated

2) If the sponsor cannot find alternative partners with experience, the R&D funding provided to the original contractor is a transaction-specific investment


Logic

The degree to which the know-how being procured is specialized to the supplier

-> A pharmaceutical company's ability to find alternative partners during a project 


Even with future projects 

Once a technological paradigm is established, one generation of product development provides the starting point for subsequent efforts (Nelson and Winter, 1977; Dosi, 1982; Tushman and Anderson, 1986).

Investments in durable assets that are specialized to the product market (such as distribution capabilities or reputation) are a source of "quasi-rents" (Monteverde and Teece, 1982b) and leave the pharmaceutical company vulnerable to rent extraction in negotiating agreements for future projects.


When alternatives are possible

When alternative partners are available, partner switching is a credible action

R&D contracts generally allow the sponsor to retain or share with the contractor the rights to the technology

The sponsor generally gets to keep for share with the contractor) technical data, materials, and other descriptive artifacts (a valuable starting point for an experienced supplier)


Hypothesis 1

the costs of market governance for a biotechnology R&D project are related to the number of R&D suppliers with R&D programs in the same product application area

Hypothesis 1: A pharmaceutical company will be more likely to internalize R&D in those biotechnology product areas in which R&D capabilities are concentrated in fewer R&D suppliers.


2) Appropriability problems

The firm not only has an interest in gaining access to both the specific and more general know-how but also in restricting rivals from using i


Conditions

1) When a project is done internally, the R&D organization can be prohibited -(by fiat) from transferring know-how to competitors. 

2) When the project is sponsored externally, however, the restriction must be incorporated into the contractual agreement.


Problems in the contraction

Problems arise in specifying all the relevant intellectual property right

+ The uncertain scope and efficacy of biotechnology patents (Cooper, 1987).


Hypothesis 2

An inability either to define or enforce intellectual property rights creates a hazard of expropriation

The number of rivals with an interest in commercializing applications of the technology

Highly competitive therapeutic markets provide an incentive for the pharmaceutical firm to internalize the development of technology

Hypothesis 2: A pharmaceutical company will be more likely to internalize R&D in those biotechnology product markets in which it faces greater competition from other established pharmaceutical companies.


- Other factors affecting R&D procurement decisions


A fundamental axiom of TCE: the boundaries of the firm are determined by the trade-off between the transaction costs of using the market and the organizational costs of using hierarchies. Coase (1937)

Economics: Factors that make the firm less efficient at either performing or governing certain activities internal

BTOF: Bounded rationality prevents firms from making optimal adjustments to environmental changes (internal organizational factor)


Historical factors_1

A firm's historical pattern of R&D procurement should affect its R&D procurement decisions in the new technological regime

First, according to a behavioral perspective of the firm, historical patterns of R&D procurement reflect deeply engrained repertoires (Simon, 1947), search rules (Cyert and March, 1963), operating procedures (Allison, 1971), and routines (Nelson and Winter, 1982).


Historical factors_2

The second way historical R&D procurement patterns affect current R&D procurement decisions is through their effect on the relative organizational costs of using either markets or hierarchies for R&D

Firms lacking experience with R&D contracting are likely to be less able to search for and select R&D partners and to absorb technologies from external sources (Westney, 1986).

Hypothesis 3: A pharmaceutical firm that tended to use in-house R&D for its traditional pharmaceutical products will have a greater propensity to internalize R&D for biotechnology-based products.


R&D experience in the relevant technology. 

Previous research on technological innovation suggests that when the technical advance is cumulative (e.g., Nelson and Winter, 1977) a firm's efficiency in performing a particular type of R&D project depends on its prior experience with similar R&D projects.

Coase's (1937) original formulation of the problem, this R&D experience reduces the costs of internalizing new R&D projects

Hypothesis 4: A pharmaceutical firm will be more likely to undertake a biotechnology R&D project in-house when it has accumulated more in-house R&D experience in the relevant area of biotechnology.


Focus. 

Decisions to expand the R&D boundaries of the firm into a new technological field are generally made at the highest levels of the corporation

One factor is the size of the pharmaceutical business relative to other businesses managed by the corporation

Hypothesis 5: A firm with a higher percentage of its business in pharmaceuticals will be more likely to internalize biotechnology- pharmaceutical R&D projects.


Firm size. 

Previous research suggests that firm size affects organizational behavior (Scherer, 1980; Miles, 1980) in general and organizational boundary decisions in particular

Anderson and Schmittlein (1984) found that in the electronics industry, the likelihood that a firm will use an internal sales force (rather than independent representatives) increases with firm size

1-1)  when expanding R&D boundaries involves fixed costs (such as new equipment and laboratory facilities), larger firms may have scale-economy advantages. 

1-2)  have more resources to invest in the development of internal capabilities. 

2) increasing size adds complexity to the administrative process, size can have a negative effect on R&D performance

Transaction-cost theorists, beginning with Coase + Clark, Chew, and Fujimoto (1987) suggested that firms can reduce the complexity of managing projects and improve project performance by using suppliers for some development tasks.


National origin. 

A firm's national-geographic origin may influence its R&D boundary choices by affecting its relative costs of undertaking R&D

# When, as in the case of biotechnology, there are national-regional differences in technological expertise, firms from one country may find it more costly to pursue R&D themselves than to purchase R&D from firms in another country better endowed with the relevant personnel and scientific expertise # My own interest


* Method


Sample_firm

R&D project-level procurement decisions

A list of the world's top 50 pharmaceutical companies in 1982 (Scrip World Pharmaceutical News in 1982)

The largest pharmaceutical firms -> Established positions in pharmaceutical markets

The largest pharmaceutical firms -> Firms that had at least some interest in commercializing biotechnology-based products

 -> Modeling backward vertical integration

The largest pharmaceutical firms -> Firms which accounted for a very significant share of the world's total efforts to commercialize new pharmaceutical products


Sample_project

1) Paine Webber's 1986 Biotechnology Fact Book

2) A database compiled by a California biotechnology firm (Drawn from public primary sources)

Prior to human clinical trials


Total

94 R&D projects across 30 of the sample firms

2 excluded for hypothesis 1

Unobserved heterogeneity -> sampling method


Mij: 1 internal, 0 external (1986)

SUPPLIERSj: the number of new biotechnology firms working in each market

RIVALSj: the number of established companies in the same area

HISTORY: Number of own R&D projects in development (1982) / All R&D products in development (1982)

EXPERIENCEij: Number of completed R&D projects by firm i in biotechnology category j

FOCUSj: the percentage of each firm's total sales attributable to its pharmaceutical business

SALES, SALES^2, log(SALES) (Firm size): pharmaceutical sales

NATION: (1) American-based, (2) European-based, or (3) Japanese-based


Mij ~ log(SUPPLIERSj) + log(RIVALSj) + EXPERIENCEij + SALES + SALES^2 + NATION

# Multicolinaerity: SUPPLIERSj & RIVALSj

# Mij as DV or IV?


* Results and discussion


H1 (supplier): O

H2 (rival): X

H3 (history): X (internalization cost) 

H4 (experience): O (Technical capabilities -> Boundary decisions) # Longitudinal analysis

# JAM JAM

H5 (focus): O (Radical core technology change (Changes of the technology regime) -> Alter strategic importance of technology)

H6 (size): X 

H7 (nation): O # Japan externalize #VOC


* Conclusion

How the structure of competition between new entrants and established firms may evolve in the wake of technological change.

# Not direct


Economies of functional or vertical specialization

However, established pharmaceutical companies undertook biotechnology R&D projects internally 
In this environment, survival may depend much more on a firm's ability to select partners and manage cooperative relationships than on its ability to develop new R&D capabilities.

Future
Buying technology -> Selling technology (biotechnology-based diagnostics)
How R&D markets work and how they may influence the organizational environment in the wake of radical technological changes
-> Technological uncertainty and the efficacy of patent protection (Levin et al., 1984; Teece, 1986)